Skip main navigation

From optimization to equilibria

To bridge the two sides of a market, the pure concept of optimization is often not enough. In this article, Hannes Weigt explains why.
© University of Basel

Up to now, we did not really have a look at markets! Your first models were following a system perspective with either you deciding about optimal investments and operation strategies or the underlying optimization model did this job based on the steering levers you chose.

Market

The building blocks of this week describe how firms and consumers behave but do not yet contain any direct interaction between the two sides. In the last model exercise, you had to choose the relevant price levels but firms and consumers reacted independently: if you chose a high electricity price you obtained plenty of supply but demand went down. You could end up with a system that was not in balance.

If you want to bring the two sides together, you will need something more: a market. However, adding a market is not as straightforward as it may sound.

The ‘job’ of markets is to bring supply and demand together and let them define the market price of the product. This price will set the incentives for firms to produce and invest in new or cleaner production facilities and the price also defines how much consumers are willing to consume of a product. While it is no problem deriving the former or the later once the price is given (basically what you did in the last model exercise), the question is how to integrate the price formation process itself into a model.

And this is where optimization models often reach their limits. Both sides of the market aim to maximize their respective benefits: firms want to maximize their profit, consumers maximize the utility they get from buying the product. The interplay between those two sides then defines the market equilibrium.

Perfect competitive market equilibrium

Simply adding up the respective objective functions of the supply and demand side is only possible under specific conditions (ie, in case of perfect competition, the market interaction can be replaced with a welfare maximization) but not in general. Here equilibrium models enter the stage. They allow us to model the interaction of markets in a mathematical setup.

In the next steps, we will gradually introduce the concept and logic of equilibrium modeling. Next week we will add the needed mathematical formulations and explain how equilibrium models allow us to interpret the economic aspects of our models.

© University of Basel
This article is from the free online

Exploring Possible Futures: Modeling in Environmental and Energy Economics

Created by
FutureLearn - Learning For Life

Our purpose is to transform access to education.

We offer a diverse selection of courses from leading universities and cultural institutions from around the world. These are delivered one step at a time, and are accessible on mobile, tablet and desktop, so you can fit learning around your life.

We believe learning should be an enjoyable, social experience, so our courses offer the opportunity to discuss what you’re learning with others as you go, helping you make fresh discoveries and form new ideas.
You can unlock new opportunities with unlimited access to hundreds of online short courses for a year by subscribing to our Unlimited package. Build your knowledge with top universities and organisations.

Learn more about how FutureLearn is transforming access to education