Skip main navigation

From one to many

Watch Hannes Weigt explaining the basic idea of oligopolies and how they fit between perfect competition and monopolies.
9.7
After leaving our rosy first best world and entering the realms of the second best world, we have made first contact with monopolies, single firms dominating their market. While there are markets out there with a dominant monopoly, many markets have more than one company, but too few to really get us back into our perfect competitive first best setting. We already know that in a perfect competitive setting, we obtain our welfare optimal result. Companies have no possibility to influence market prices and take those as given. In the end, we have the allocative efficient solution. And prices are equal to marginal costs. On the other side of the spectrum, we have the monopoly.
62.7
Being able to influence the prices, the monopoly will exercise market power to push those up until it maximises its own profit. Compared with the perfect competitive world, we end up the less satisfied demand at a higher market price. In between those two extremes, we have what economists term an oligopoly, a market with a few larger firms, a pretty common real world market setting. Just think about cars, supermarkets, or telecommunication. Also, many energy markets have oligopolistic structures. And the industry sectors, subject to environmental policies, may be structured as oligopolies as well. So how should we deal with oligopolies and economic modelling? First, they are also part of the second best world.
125.1
We still try to get the best outcome that is possible within those conditions. Second, there are different types of oligopolies and different concepts how to model them, like Cournot, or Bertrand competition, or Stackelberg’s leader / follower setting. It will take a separate course to discuss them all. The basic concept of oligopoly models is that the firm, i, knows that it has an influence on the price and so do the competing firms indicated by the minus i. Given this information, the firm still tries to do what every company is doing, maximising profits. Consequently, many oligopoly model approaches fall into the realm of equilibrium modelling to capture the interaction between firms.
183.8
Being placed between the benchmark of perfect and monopolistic competition, the oligopolistic market results also fall between those two extremes. The closer you get to one side of the axis, the closer the market results typically converge to their respective benchmark. If you have a duopoly, your results normally will tend closer to the monopoly results than if you have 5 or 10 firms, which then usually tend closer to the competitive benchmark results. Oligopoly models are some of the most interesting settings to study, but they often have challenging mathematical properties. So expect to rely on simplifications when designing your own ones.
234.6
Often, it is helpful to derive to two benchmarks first before venturing into the world of oligopolies, not only to get to reference points, which you may compare your oligopoly to, but also to get a basic understanding of your model before adding the complexity of oligopolistic competition.

Now that we have introduced monopolies to our modeling world we can go one step further by introducing oligopolies.

For many markets perfect competition is more of a theoretic benchmark. But the same often also holds for monopolistic competition. While there are markets dominated by one large company many governments aim to prevent a pure monopoly market. Often real world markets are characterized by what economists term oligopolistic competition: a few large companies dominating the market.

The basic concept of oligopoly models is that the firms know that they have an influence on the price and take this into account when maximizing their profits. However, compared to a monopoly each firm in an oligopoly only has partial influence on market prices. Consequently, equilibrium models are a preferred approach to model oligopolistic markets.

There are many different economic oligopoly concepts. Many of them follow the structure that with more firms the results tend towards a more competitive market behaviour and vice versa. Deriving the perfectly competitive and monopoly benchmark therefore provides valuable benchmark conditions for oligopoly models.

This article is from the free online

Exploring Possible Futures: Modeling in Environmental and Energy Economics

Created by
FutureLearn - Learning For Life

Our purpose is to transform access to education.

We offer a diverse selection of courses from leading universities and cultural institutions from around the world. These are delivered one step at a time, and are accessible on mobile, tablet and desktop, so you can fit learning around your life.

We believe learning should be an enjoyable, social experience, so our courses offer the opportunity to discuss what you’re learning with others as you go, helping you make fresh discoveries and form new ideas.
You can unlock new opportunities with unlimited access to hundreds of online short courses for a year by subscribing to our Unlimited package. Build your knowledge with top universities and organisations.

Learn more about how FutureLearn is transforming access to education